5.1 Demand for labour
DEFINITIONS:
- Derived demand for labour: The demand for labour that arises from the demand for the goods and services that labour helps to produce.
- Productivity: The measure of output produced per unit of input, typically expressed as output per worker or output per hour worked.
- Unit labour costs: The average cost of labour per unit of output, calculated as total labour costs divided by total output.
- Wage elasticity of the demand for labour: measures the responsiveness of the quantity of labour demanded by employers to changes in the wage rate.
Explain
5.1.1 Derived demand for labour
Derived demand for labour refers to the demand for workers that arises from the demand for the goods and services they produce. In other words, labour is not demanded for its own sake but because it contributes to the production process that results in goods and services that are sold in the market.
Key Points:
- Indirect Demand: The demand for labour is indirect. It depends on the demand for the final product. For instance, if there is a high demand for cars, the demand for automotive workers will also be high.
- Factor of Production: Labour is considered a factor of production, along with capital, land, and entrepreneurship. Firms demand labour because it helps them produce goods and services.
- Marginal Productivity: The demand for labour is influenced by the marginal productivity of workers. This is the additional output produced by an additional unit of labour. If a worker can significantly contribute to production, their demand will be higher.
- Wage Rates: The wage rate is determined by the interaction of the demand for and supply of labour. Higher productivity and higher demand for the product can lead to higher wage rates for workers.
- Economic Conditions: The overall economic environment, including factors such as consumer demand, technological changes, and government policies, affects the derived demand for labour. For example, a recession can lead to a decrease in demand for products, thereby reducing the demand for labour.
- Substitution Effect: Firms may substitute labour with capital if it becomes more cost-effective. For example, if wages rise significantly, a firm might invest in automation to reduce its reliance on labour.
- Complementary Goods: The demand for labour can also be influenced by the demand for complementary goods and services. For instance, an increase in the demand for personal computers can increase the demand for software developers.
In summary, the derived demand for labour highlights the dependency of labour demand on the demand for the final products and services that labour helps to produce. Understanding this concept is crucial in analysing how labour markets function and how various economic factors influence employment and wage levels.
5.1.2 Factors affecting the demand for labour in an industry
- Productivity of Labour:
- Higher productivity increases the marginal revenue product (MRP) of labour, making workers more valuable to employers.
- This can lead to an increase in the demand for labour as firms seek to hire more productive workers.
- Wage Rates:
- There is an inverse relationship between wage rates and the quantity of labour demanded.
- As wage rates decrease, the cost of hiring labour falls, making it more attractive for firms to employ more workers.
- Conversely, higher wages can reduce the demand for labour.
- Demand for the Final Product:
- Derived demand: The demand for labour is dependent on the demand for the goods and services that labour produces.
- An increase in the demand for a firm's products can lead to an increase in the demand for labour to produce those goods.
- Technology:
- Technological advancements can either complement or substitute labour.
- Complementary technology (e.g., new tools that make workers more efficient) can increase the demand for labour.
- Substitutive technology (e.g., automation) can reduce the demand for labour by replacing human workers.
- Cost of Capital:
- The cost of alternative inputs, such as capital, can affect the demand for labour.
- If the cost of capital decreases (e.g., cheaper machinery), firms might substitute labour with capital, reducing the demand for labour.
- Conversely, if capital becomes more expensive, firms may rely more on labour.
- Number of Firms in the Industry:
- An increase in the number of firms within an industry can increase the overall demand for labour.
- Conversely, consolidation within an industry (e.g., mergers) can reduce the demand for labour as firms achieve economies of scale.
- Regulation and Government Policies:
- Labour market regulations, such as minimum wage laws, employment protection legislation, and taxes on labour, can influence the demand for labour.
- Policies that increase the cost of hiring (e.g., higher minimum wages) can decrease the demand for labour, while policies that reduce hiring costs (e.g., tax incentives) can increase it.
- Economic Conditions:
- The overall economic climate affects the demand for labour.
- During periods of economic growth, firms are more likely to expand and hire more workers.
- During recessions, demand for labour tends to decrease as firms cut back on production and employment.
- Skills and Qualifications of the Workforce:
- The availability and quality of skilled workers can affect the demand for labour.
- Industries requiring high-skilled labour may see increased demand if there is a sufficient supply of qualified workers.
- A lack of skilled workers can constrain the demand for labour.
These factors collectively influence how much labour firms are willing and able to hire at any given wage rate, determining the overall demand for labour within an industry.
5.1.3 Factors affecting wage elasticity of demand for labour
Wage elasticity of demand for labour measures the responsiveness of the quantity of labour demanded by firms to changes in the wage rate. Several factors influence this elasticity:
- Substitutability of Labour:
- If labour can be easily substituted with capital (machines) or other inputs, the demand for labour is more elastic. For instance, in industries where automation is feasible, a rise in wages may lead firms to replace workers with machines.
- Proportion of Labour Costs in Total Costs:
- If labour costs constitute a significant portion of total costs, the demand for labour tends to be more elastic. This is because a wage increase significantly raises total production costs, prompting firms to reduce their labour demand.
- Price Elasticity of Demand for the Final Product:
- If the product's demand is price elastic, the demand for labour is also more elastic. This occurs because higher wages lead to higher product prices, resulting in a considerable drop in quantity demanded and thus a significant reduction in labour demand.
- Time Period:
- In the short run, the demand for labour is generally more inelastic because firms cannot easily change their production methods or substitute capital for labour. Over the long run, firms have more flexibility to adjust to wage changes, making the demand for labour more elastic.
- Availability of Skilled Labour:
- For highly specialized or skilled labour, demand tends to be inelastic because such workers are not easily replaced. Conversely, for unskilled labour that is readily available, demand is more elastic.
- Nature of the Industry:
- Industries characterized by rapid technological advancements or frequent changes in production methods typically have more elastic labour demand, as firms can more readily adapt to wage changes by altering their use of labour.
Understanding these factors helps in analysing how wage changes might impact employment levels within different sectors of the economy.
5.1.4 Productivity and unit labour costs
Productivity
Productivity measures the efficiency with which inputs are converted into outputs in the production process. It is typically expressed as output per unit of input. The most common form of productivity measurement is labour productivity, which is calculated as:
Labour Productivity=Number of Workers or Hours WorkedTotal Output​
Higher productivity indicates that more output is being produced per worker or per hour worked, which can lead to economic growth, higher wages, and increased competitiveness for firms.
Unit Labour Costs
Unit Labour Costs (ULC) represent the average cost of labour per unit of output. It reflects the cost competitiveness of a firm's labour force and is calculated as:
Unit Labour Costs=Total OutputTotal Labour Costs​
Alternatively, it can be expressed as:
UnitLabourCosts=Unit Labour Costs=Labour ProductivityAverage Wage​
An increase in unit labour costs means that labour has become more expensive relative to the output produced, which can reduce a firm's competitiveness unless it can pass on these costs to consumers through higher prices. Conversely, a decrease in unit labour costs indicates improved cost efficiency, enhancing the firm's competitiveness.
Key Points
- Productivity improvements can reduce unit labour costs if wages remain constant, making firms more competitive.
- Conversely, if wages rise faster than productivity, unit labour costs increase, potentially harming competitiveness.
- Both metrics are crucial for understanding economic performance, wage dynamics, and the competitive position of businesses in both domestic and international markets.
Understanding these concepts helps in analysing the efficiency and cost dynamics within an economy, and their implications for growth, inflation, and competitiveness.
Explain with aid of a diagram
5.1.5 Marginal Revenue Product Theory in Relation to Employment and Wage Determination
Marginal Revenue Product (MRP) Theory: This theory states that the demand for labour is derived from the additional revenue generated by employing one more unit of labour. The MRP is calculated by multiplying the marginal product of labour (MPL) by the marginal revenue (MR) that the additional output generates.
MRP=MPLĂ—MR
Key Concepts:
- Marginal Product of Labour (MPL): The additional output produced by one more unit of labour.
- Marginal Revenue (MR): The additional revenue from selling the extra output produced by one more unit of labour.
Diagram Explanation:
Below is a simplified diagram illustrating the MRP theory:
Explanation:
- MRP Curve: The downward-sloping MRP curve indicates that as more labour is employed, the additional revenue generated by each additional worker decreases due to the law of diminishing returns.
- Wage Rate (W): The equilibrium wage rate is determined by the intersection of the MRP curve and the supply of labour curve (S).
Determination of Employment:
- Firms hire labour up to the point where the MRP equals the wage rate (W). This is because firms seek to maximize profit and will hire additional workers as long as the MRP of the last worker employed is greater than or equal to the wage rate.
- If MRP > Wage Rate, hiring more workers increases profit.
- If MRP < Wage Rate, hiring more workers decreases profit.
Wage Determination:
- In a competitive labour market, the wage rate is determined by the intersection of the supply of labour (S) and the demand for labour (MRP).
- The equilibrium wage rate (W) and the equilibrium quantity of labour (L) are determined at this intersection point.
Key Points:
- Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns: As more units of labour are employed, the additional output produced by each additional unit of labour decreases, causing the MRP to fall.
- Profit Maximization: Firms maximize profit by employing labour up to the point where the MRP equals the wage rate.
- Competitive Labour Market: In a competitive market, the wage rate is determined by the intersection of the labour supply (S) and labour demand (MRP).